ISSN (Print) - 0012-9976 | ISSN (Online) - 2349-8846

A+| A| A-

The Dragon and the Elephant: Learning from Agricultural and Rural Reforms in China and India

What can we learn from the process of economic reform in China and India? Does the sequencing of reform and an agriculture-led package matter? What could other developing countries and countries in economic transition learn from the experiences of India and China? What could these two countries learn from their own as well as each other's experiences? How can the two largest developing countries cooperate in their agricultural and economic development and work together at multilateral negotiations, such as those conducted through the World Trade Organisation, to address the concerns of developing countries? This paper summarises the key findings of a number of studies that were prepared for two international conferences devoted to comparing the rural development and agricultural reform experiences of China (the dragon) and India (the elephant) over the last several decades.

REVIEW OF AGRICULTUREEconomic & Political Weekly EPW june 28, 2008137The Dragon and the Elephant: Learning from Agricultural and Rural Reforms in China and IndiaShenggen Fan, Ashok GulatiWhat can we learn from the process of economic reform in China and India? Does the sequencing of reform and an agriculture-led package matter? What could other developing countries and countries in economic transition learn from the experiences of India and China? What could these two countries learn from their own as well as each other’s experiences? How can the two largest developing countries cooperate in their agricultural and economic development and work together at multilateral negotiations, such as those conducted through the World Trade Organisation, to address the concerns of developing countries? This paper summarises the key findings of a number of studies that were prepared for two international conferences devoted to comparing the rural development and agricultural reform experiences of China (the dragon) and India (the elephant) over the last several decades.Shenggen Fan (s.fan@cgiar.org) is with the Development Strategy and Governance Division, International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington DC, United States, and Ashok Gulati (a.gulati@cgiar.org) is the Asia director of the International Food Policy Research Institute, New Delhi.Today, China and India together account for 40 per cent of the world’s population. Both have implemented a series of economic reforms in the past two and half decades: China initiated this process at the end of the 1970s, while India began in the early 1990s. 1 IntroductionThe reforms in both India and China have led to rapid economic growth, with growth rates touching 9-10 per cent per annum in China and 8-9 per cent per annum in India in recent years. De-spite similar trends in the growth rates, the two countries have taken different reform paths; China started off with reforms in the agriculture sector and in rural areas, while India started by liberal-ising and reforming the manufacturing sector. These differences have led to different growth rates and, more importantly, different rates of poverty reduction. They also have fundamentally different implications for growth and poverty reduction in the future.What can we learn from the process of economic reform in these two countries? Does the sequencing of reform and an agriculture-led package matter? What could other developing countries and countries in economic transition learn from the experiences of India and China? What could these two countries learn from their own as well as each other’s experiences? How can the two largest developing countries cooperate in their agricultural and economic development and work together at multilateral negotiations, such as those conducted through the World Trade Organisation (WTO), to address the concerns of developing countries? This paper summarises the key findings of a number of studies that were prepared for two international conferences devoted to comparing the rural development and agricultural reform experi-ences of China (the dragon) and India (the elephant) over the last several decades.1 These are as follows: 2 Agricultural Reforms for Poverty ReductionFrom the trend growth rates of agriculture and the incidence of poverty in the pre- and post-reform periods in China, it is clear that the acceleration in agricultural growth during 1978-2002 (4.6 per cent a year as opposed to 2.5 per cent a year over 1966-77) was the primary factor influencing the sharp drop in poverty, from 33 per cent of the population in 1978 to 3 per cent in 2001 [NBS 2002]. The better part of this decline occurred in the first reform phase of 1978-84 when agricultural gross domestic product (GDP) jumped to 7.1 per cent a year and rural poverty dropped from 33 per cent to 15 per cent. In India, the most rapid poverty reduction occurred
China India
China India China India
REVIEW OF AGRICULTUREEconomic & Political Weekly EPW june 28, 2008139was a natural choice for India since the incentive structure of Indian agriculture was highly distorted at the outset of reforms; the sector was, and still is, burdened with excessive regulations on private trading and most market activities. There is significant potential for growth only if these constraints are removed. In the case of India, liberalisation of agricultural trade policies happened to create a series of imbalances by preceding incentive and market reforms in the domestic arena. Lowered protection against a backdrop of low international prices increased imports, although in the case of wheat there was already excess supply from domestic production induced by a high minimum support price (MSP). While broad-based economic and trade reforms re-sulted in the new export orientation of the sector and improved the incentive framework of agriculture, they also left the sector more exposed to international competition because of persisting constraints to productivity improvement in the domestic front.2 As a result, India is now attempting marketing reforms and removal of regulatory constraints at least in some of the states by amending Agriculture Produce Marketing Committee Act, al-though Essential Commodities Act still remains in place.4 Importance of Initial Conditions In 1970 the likelihood of an Indian child dying before the fifth birthday was twice that of her Chinese counterpart. Life expectancy was 49 years in India against China’s 62 years, and 70 per cent of the Indian rural population was illiterate as opposed to 49 per cent of rural Chinese [WDI 2006]. One important reason for China’s edge over India in health and education is the collective system where the government provided these basic amenities free. Rural electrification had made headway in the pre-reform years as rural electricity consumption grew at a rate of 27 per cent a year over 1953-80 as opposed to 10 per cent a year over 1980-90 and govern-ment investment in power grew at 27 per cent a year during 1953-78 [Fan, Zhang and Zhang 2002]. The egalitarian access to land was ensured by the land distribution and tenure system which also performed a crucial welfare function by limiting the number of the landless, providing the bulk of the rural population with subsist-ence and helping to distribute widely the benefits from agricul-tural price and market reform. The resultant improvement in effi-ciency and productivity were major triggers in poverty reduction.In India on the other hand, land reforms to make the agrarian structure more equitable were not as successful and left a relatively larger number of landless agricultural labourers exposed to the harsh impact of unemployment and underemployment. In the power sector too, although public investments were substantial, annual growth of 12 per cent during 1981-90 [Fan, Gulati and Thorat 2007] was not as high as in China and thus rural electrification and even es-tablishment of telecommunication connection proceeded more slowly in the Indian villages. This slow pace severely affected the growth of agro-processing and cold storage in the rural non-farm sector. The levels of processing remain abysmal even now, with over 20 per cent of fruit and vegetables produced going waste, and the government is currently designing policies to encourage this sector. Thus, the relatively more favourable initial conditions in China help to explain why, despite the private and economic restrictions imposed on the Chinese rural population, the country could achieve a sustained growth even before the reforms [NBS 2003].3 However, China could not fully realise the benefits from the available physical and social infrastructure in the pre-reform period because of lack of incentives under the commune system. Once economic reforms were introduced, they released the latent energy in the system, resulting in a very high growth rate and rapid reduction in poverty after the 1970s [Rao 2003].Both countries recorded a slowdown in meeting their health and education goals after reforms began. In India, this was primarily due to the fiscal discipline imposed by the macroeconomic crisis, while market-oriented reforms in China introduced the concept of profit in the management of social services. In China, this implied progressive privatisation of supply agencies, decline in government subsidies, and increase in education and health costs, which caused school dropouts and rising health vulnerability. In devising mechanisms to address the risks involved in increased privatisation of social services, China could perhaps learn from India’s long experience of a vast system of government safety nets and welfare programmes for the rural population. With regard to land, both countries have high population-land ratios but distribution is less skewed in China than in India and landlessness is virtually absent. As in education and health, equal access to land was a product of the egalitarianism inherent in the collective era that played a vital role in minimising risks and ensuring the availability of minimum subsistence. In India, replication of the Chinese agrarian system is not politically fea-sible, so marginal and landless farmers will require a strong social protection system through well-targeted social security and employment policies. Effective social protection measures will also be required in China where land distribution is likely to become skewed and more concentrated following the adoption of the new agricultural lease law that enables farmers to transfer lease rights.Both China and India are characterised by the predominance of small farms (below two hectares) – more so in China – which has implications for rural employment. China’s experience shows that small farms support more intensive use of family labour resources, while in India, owners of holdings above two hectares, who ac-count for less than 20 per cent of total landholdings but over 60 per cent of cultivated area, often lack the incentive to practise labour-intensive cultivation.Therefore, reforms are required to optimise land use and eliminate distortions such as concealed tenancy in Indian land markets. Land leasing is restricted affecting private investment as well as the scope for consolidation into larger and more efficient operational holdings [Landes and Gulati 2003]. However, given the high population-land ratio, approach to de-regulation is naturally cautious, allowing for a minimum set of safeguards (for example, liberalising leasing within ceilings) to prevent absentee landlordism and increase in landlessness.5 PublicInvestmentsIn China, the correlation between the initial conditions and post-reform achievements in poverty reduction and growth makes a convincing case for stepping upgovernment investments in rural infrastructure and social services. In India, on the other hand, the decline in rural public investment as a result of fiscal profligacy
REVIEW OF AGRICULTUREjune 28, 2008 EPW Economic & Political Weekly140and rising subsidies on fertilisers, power, water and price support is regarded as a primary cause of slower growth after 1997. Since both these countries have budget pressures and are unlikely to be able to raise public investments significantly, they would just have to invest available resources more efficiently. Returns to public investments vary drastically across different types of investment and regions even within the same country. This implies a great potential for achieving more growth and less poverty even with the same amount of investment, assuming public resources can be allocated optimally on the basis of reliable information on the marginal returns of different government spending. Studies have found that spending on agricultural research, education, and rural roads is the most effective for promoting agricultural growth and poverty reduction [Fan, Gulati and Thorat 2007]. Then again, both countries will find it tough to expand cultivable land and water resources, so yield-based farm growth will become important and will call for increased agricultural research and technology development. Agricultural research and development (R&D) takes place in both public and private sectors, but managing public versus private R&D can be tricky. China pro-moted the development of the public business sector through commercialisation of technologies by public research institutes but this often led to duplication of research and overlap of efforts withSOEs. The Chinese experience can provide valuable lessons in this sector for other countries in transition.The improved intellectual property right (IPR) regime under WTO stimulated private research and patenting activity in both countries [Pal 2004]. However, weak implementation ofIPR in the two countries and high costs of maintaining patents in China are obstacles to the entry of private players. The Chinese experience also shows that protection of plant varieties can help improve resource generation by the poorer public research institutes as the number ofIPR applications filed was effectively higher for resource-poor institutions than for better-funded national institutes. In terms of increasing the scope for private research, India’s case indicate that theIPR regime is more effective if comple-mented byfavourable policies in the area of tax, investment and input imports (ibid). Private agriculturalR&D provides both opportunities and challenges. Significant opportunities can arise for public-private partnerships in the areas of funding, research and extension. However policymakers need to be aware that the private sector tends to privilege higher-value crops and concentrate in areas where agriculture is already advanced. Given agriculture R&D’s potential to reduce poverty in marginal regions, public research spending should target poorer farmers in less favoured environ-ments like India’s semi-arid tropics and rainfed areas and China’s poor western regions.Water Management and ConservationIn the water sector, government spending in irrigation effectively promoted growth and poverty reduction, but the marginal returns of such spending has come down over time. Indeed, stud-ies have shown that investments in rainfed areas have had high marginal returns for agricultural growth and poverty reduction. Major investments in harvesting rainwater through watersheds, through public-private partnerships, may help usher in a “multi-coloured revolution” (not just a “green” one) in agriculture. In both countries, water use efficiency can be vastly improved through institutional and management reforms of existing water systems. India’s experience with water users’ associations (WUA) in some states, participatory watershed schemes and community-based rain harvesting can provide good learning experience. Transfer of management to user groups was more successful in India, although the coverage of irrigated areas by these user associations remains low in India compared to other south-east Asian countries [Rao 2002]. Insufficient administrative and political will to devolve management powers to the local WUAs and inadequate infrastructure for building capacity inhibited the involvement of farmers in India [Rao 2000]. On the other hand, the Chinese experience shows that reforms aimed at giving incentives to irrigation systems managers to improve use-efficiency had a positive effect on crop yields, groundwater table and cereal production [Wang et al 2003]. The question is whether the strategy of transforming water bureaucrats into managers is possible in India.Providing right incentives to farmers is crucial to promoting water saving. Low water prices and profligate power subsidies for operating tubewells have encouraged wasteful use of water and depletion of groundwater resources. Ambiguous water use rights following de-collectivisation in China, and laws linking water rights to land ownership in India also led to inefficiencies. These included the emergence of unfair water markets over time, where rich landholders with modern water extraction technology prof-ited from selling water to poorer cultivators. Increase in water use charges may not be feasible in the short to medium term without changes in the institutional set-up. In India, irrigation is affected by realpolitik as free electricity for pumping water is offered for political rent-seeking. In both coun-tries, given the booming numbers of private tubewell owners and weak institutions and infrastructure that make monitoring of water withdrawals and revenue collection difficult,4 the impact of reforms like withdrawal permit systems and volumetric charg-ing can only be limited [Shah, Scott and Buechler 2004; Wang, Huang and Rozelle 2003]. Improved crop yields can also lead to a more efficient use of scarce water resources in agriculture. For that, inputs other than water, such as credit and agricultural research on water saving and yield-improving technologies, need to be deployed. This is particularly true for India where both irrigated and rainfed crop yields are lower than those in China. In both countries, this may also call for trade and price policies favourable to high-value, less water-intensive crops. In India, technological innovations to improve yields seem more feasible in the short and medium term than management reforms for im-proving water use efficiency, given the political and institutional constraints [Rao 2002]. 6 ReformIncentives China’s experience with marketing reforms holds valuable les-sons for other transition economies. Farm support policies lose their rationale when there is oversupply of food and agricultural trade is free and open. IndianMSPs and input subsidies were
REVIEW OF AGRICULTUREEconomic & Political Weekly EPW june 28, 2008141intended to encourage the adoption of new technologies and fuel growth, turned into inefficient and costly income-support inter-ventions, encouraging the build-up of vested interests because they were not abolished after their aim was realised. China could learn from this experience and seek to encourage agricultural growth in the future, yet avoid the large inefficient Indian subsi-dies. This issue is important because India has recently intro-duced a costly direct transfer programme for rural areas and also because of late, increasing government support to agriculture and rural areas is finding many takers among scholars and government officials alike.Despite limited reforms in agricultural marketing in India, the impact of policy changes has slowed down since state govern-ments are reluctant to implement them [Landes and Gulati 2003]. In addition, a host of outdated domestic regulations, such as the agricultural price marketing committee (APMC) acts, regulation of agricultural produce market sale, restrictive land laws and licence requirements on food processing units, continue to weaken the environment for agribusiness and private sector involvement in agricultural marketing that could boost employment and efficiency. In the backdrop of increasing, diversified food demand and opening up of agricultural trade, legal and regulatory reform remains critical given its capacity to directly impact the sector adjusting to the changing environment. Given that smallholder agriculture is predominant in both countries, farmers could be excessively penalised because they do not possess sufficient capital and information to manage the risks inherent in agricul-tural activities. While China and India are reconsidering the cur-rent forms of agricultural and input subsidies, they should also put in place well-targeted and innovative cost-effective crop insurance policies to protect farmers vulnerable to drastic supply and price shocks. Such shocks can only intensify as trade policies are further liberalised. In India, the abolition of restrictions to trading on the futures markets in major agricultural commodities is a step in this direction, which needs to be further strengthened. One other important area is the strengthening of the network of support services to small farmers related to information, credit and extension. The Indian experience shows that smallholder agriculture needs strong institutional support in these areas to grow and prosper.Trade LiberalisationWith regard to broad trade liberalisation, both countries made progress in reducing protection levels. Still, India’s weighted average tariff at 29 per cent was double that of China’s 16 per cent [Ahluwalia 2002]. India was able to sustain its current growth rate with lower foreign direct investment (FDI) inflows and a relatively less export orientation than China. But if it has to attain the target of 9 per cent GDP growth it needs to further reform theFDI climate in view of its potential to transfer know-how, managerial skills and new technologies. China can offer valuable lessons in this area. The inevitable restructuring and adjustments involved in opening up agricultural trade flows will produce both winners and losers. Domestic producers of crops in which the country lacks comparative advantage (for example, edible oils in the case of India and wheat and maize for China) are likely to suffer in-creasingly from falling prices resulting from higher imports. They will also be negatively affected when there is pressure on the governments to reduce support to inefficient national producers. Broad-based structural adjustments in the economy may depress rural income, increase opportunities in manufacturing as well as services primarily located in urban areas, and widen rural-urban inequality. These inter-sectoral adjustments will progressively shrink the size of the primary sector, which will release addi-tional unskilled labour into the labour markets.The rural population will gain if it is able to shift to more prof-itable off-farm occupations. Here, investment in rural education can help farmers move out of traditional occupations. It will also be important to increase investments in ruralR&D and infrastruc-ture to enhance productivity. These investments fall under the WTO “green box” and are therefore exempted from reduction commitments, although their positive impact will be realised over the longer run. On the positive side, WTO membership can provide the much-needed external pressure to improve efficiency and implement reforms in tradable inputs such as seeds, fertilis-ers, farm machinery and pesticides, where markets are inefficient either due to government intervention or lack of infrastructure. It can also highlight the facilitating role of the government in the provision of services like information, marketing facilities, tech-nical assistance, and standards and quality control regulations. Lastly,WTO also offers an opportunity to join hands and create a third force of countries besides the giants European Union (EU) and the US in negotiations during the Doha round. 7 PromotingRuralDiversification A major shift in farm production towards non-foodgrain products like livestock, fishery and horticulture has been well under way in India and China since the 1980s. In China, achievement of food self-sufficiency and the extraordinary growth in basic grain pro-duction by the late 1970s immensely helped diversification. This is because food surpluses provided government with enough lee-way to feed the increasing population and relax controls over the foodgrain sector. China gradually abandoned the policies biased in favour of rice and wheat, such as the food rationing system for urban areas or the mandatory levy quotas, which encouraged farmers to diversify production. Developing countries affected by chronic food shortages can learn from this experience. In contrast, steadily growingMSPs in India artificially raised pro-duction of major cereals discouraging diversification toward non-grain commodities.A comparison of the shares of government expenditure to the pace of growth in output in different agricultural sub-sectors in-dicate that despite high growth, some high value products (like livestock and horticulture) are under-funded relative to tradi-tional food crops [Pal 2004]. Policymakers must encourage higher investment in research to boost yields and expand cultiva-tion given the export potential of these crops, positive impact on smallholders, and growing domestic demand.Post-reforms, rising per capita income influencing food con-sumption patterns has been a major driver for diversification into non-food crops. Without vertical integration between production,
REVIEW OF AGRICULTUREjune 28, 2008 EPW Economic & Political Weekly142processing and marketing – that is, between “plate and plough” – the potential for growth inherent in the diversification process may remain under-exploited. Vertical integration reduces risks by providing assured markets, cuts transactions costs, and helps improve quality standards and food safety. In both countries, new and innovative institutional arrangements have emerged, promoting the development of new products, and these need to be strengthened. India’s successful experiments with contract farming, which helped cut risk, promote production and export of high-value foods, and raise income and employment of small-holders, can be valuable for China. On the other hand, the experi-ence of growth in the retail food chains and supermarkets in China in recent years could benefit India where restrictions on FDI and infrastructure bottlenecks are limiting progress. InadequaciesIn smallholder dominated farming, diversification has important implications for poverty reduction. The labour-intensive nature of the production of high-value products is not only well suited to the small farm economy but there is also great potential for employ-ment creation in agro-processing and retail chains. Strengthening vertical integration through innovative institutional arrangements without tackling the other major obstacles faced by the small farmers would not be effective in reducing poverty. In fact, India’s case shows how institutional deficiencies like weak enforcement of contracts and high transaction costs faced by small cultivators often prompt agro-firms to deal directly with large farmers. Acceleration of diversification in favour of small farmers is also hindered by lack of access to markets, technology and informa-tion, poor rural infrastructure and inadequate marketing facilities. Future reforms need to address these issues through increased in-vestments in basic rural infrastructure and marketing facilities like cold storage chains. Lastly, small cultivators often lack sufficient marketable surplus. Nor can they raise production at will due to their lack of access to technology and financial services. Well-targeted government support services are needed in credit markets and extension services designed specifically for smallholders.Rural Non-Farm SectorLooking away from crops, as the Chinese experience has amply demonstrated, the evolution of a dynamic rural non-farm sector offers great potential for rural diversification. Rapid growth of rural enterprises in China is one of the most striking differentiators between the reform processes of the two countries, especially as township and village enterprises (TVEs) provided increasing jobs outside agriculture, by diversifying and expanding the sources of household income. Agricultural growth and favourable demand conditions were critical to development of the RNF sector in China because post-1978, reforms triggered a surge in demand from prospering rural areas for TVE products. TVEs also benefited from the close connection with dynamic urban markets established since the early stages of their development. The connection with urban markets brought TVEs in competition withSOEs and stimu-lated the latter to increase productivity and unit scale [ILO 1998]. In India, however, farm output growth rates decelerated, damp-ening demand as well as farm and non-farm employment.India’s non-farm economy produces low-profit services of the informal sector primarily for the rural markets and is dominated by tiny own-account family-operated units. These are character-ised by low productivity brought about by poor technological base and by policies aimed at protecting rural employment by reserving certain activities for small units. Limited growth of RNF job opportunities is also related to the poorly educated rural labour force. This is a challenge that will increasingly confront both countries as they adjust to greater market and trade liberali-sation leading to economic restructuring and the replacement of traditional and low-productivity jobs by new and more produc-tive occupations requiring more educated labourers. Thus spend-ing on rural education will be crucial.The role of non-farm employment is expected to become in-creasingly significant as the average size of farms get smaller. Small farms may be efficient in terms of land productivity but not in labour productivity, which is more closely linked to farmers’ income. Greater off-farm opportunities and migration to urban areas is required to increase average farm size, labour producti-vity and farmers’ income.8 Anti-PovertyProgrammes The role of anti-poverty programmes (APPs) and safety nets in poverty alleviation came into sharp focus in the 1990s to address the negative impact of liberal policies on income distribution. The need for fiscal stabilisation in India meant the reduction in transfers to the states and in capital expenditures on rural infra-structure [Jha 2000], to counterbalance which the government stepped up funding for several existing anti-poverty programmes and created new ones. In China, the government was strongly committed to addressing the poverty problem, and government initiatives, as announced in official plans and government con-ferences starting in the mid-1990s, were revived.Poverty funds and programmes have documented shortfalls and inefficiencies in terms of targeting and cost-effectiveness, but their significant contribution to limiting the severity and the extent of poverty is inescapable. There are still more than 400 million rural poor in India and China, based on the international standard of one dollar a day (more than 100 million in China and more than 300 million in India). In China, the bulk of the rural poor are primarily in the remote, mountainous or natural-resource poor western provinces. In India, they are concentrated in the eastern (Bihar, Orissa and West Bengal), central (Madhya Pradesh) and northern (Uttar Pradesh) states where rural poverty is higher than the all-India average of 27 per cent as of 2004-05.Radical redistributive measures like land reforms are relatively impractical in India due to their potential for social conflict, while public investments take a long time to translate into employment and economic growth. Compared to these,APPs are a more agile instrument in the short run, provided their shortcomings are removed.5 Poor design, targeting, implementation and fund mis-use are key causes of ineffective poverty programmes. To improve targeting, one lesson that China may draw from the experience of India is in the use of a greater variety of targeted programmes directed to specific sections of the poor as opposed to its own
REVIEW OF AGRICULTUREEconomic & Political Weekly EPW june 28, 2008143traditional, broader income or area-based approaches. Self- selection schemes like rural public works and plans targeting women, children and the elderly are more pro-poor since identifi-cation of the beneficiaries are easier, faster and less costly. To strengthen the impact ofAPPs, decentralised and participa-tory approaches are more effective than top-down strategies as they involve a greater variety of agents (non-governmental organisations (NGOs), civil society, and international aid organi-sations) in the fight against poverty besides the government. India is a good point of reference in this respect since extensive participation of panchayats and civil society at various stages of the formulation and implementation of the programmes ensures the tailoring of programmes to local needs, thereby improving their impact and effectiveness.9 Institutions and Regulatory Environment In both countries there was political will to carry out reforms, but in practice outcomes were shaped by the different patterns of governance. India is a “debating society” where political differ-ences are expressed freely. Policymaking is exposed to the pressure of various interest groups and there are long debates before decisions are taken. The lengthy bureaucratic procedures, intended to ensure checks and balances in the system, often de-lays decision-making and implementation. This exercise is com-patible with the needs of a free and dynamic polity but in practice is a key reason for India’s slow pace of economic reforms. China, on the other hand, is a “mobilising society” where deci-sions are taken faster and state power is backed by mass mobili-sation. As a result, implementation of decisions is more effective although the lack of more elaborate debate in China on major reforms can sometimes lead to disastrous actions, as with the Great Leap Forward in 1958, and the Cultural Revolution of 1966-76. Interestingly, as the economic system opens up further and prosperity increases, it will become harder and harder to reconcile the centralised political set-up with the more liberal economic system. Indeed, this is one of the most important challenges before China today. However, in China, the ideology-induced commitment to build an equitable society in the pre-reform years created a strong political will to provide the population with near-universal accessto basic health and education services, while the administrative set-up of the communes proved an effective mechanism of resource mobilisation and service delivery. Although similar administrative machinery is not replicable in the Indian context, the country can still try and strengthen the initial conditions in terms of rural electrification, roads, access to education and health services etc. A critical factor in explaining dissimilar reform outcomes be-tween India and China is the difference at the level of reform im-plementation that is shaped by the institutional, regulatory and political settings. Investments in rural infrastructure and other key public services are crucial, but it is equally critical to develop suitable institutional arrangements for their delivery. Major fail-ures in public provision notwithstanding, the government con-tinues to be the major supplier of infrastructure services in both countries. Input suppliers like the state electricity boards (SEBs) in India and SOEs (including grain bureaus) in China do not function efficiently due to the lack of transparency and accountability.As against the requirement of a 3 per cent return on investment (RoI),SEBs have recorded negativeRoIs since 1981. By 2000-01, their returns were a negative 27 per cent after subsidies [Gulati and Narayanan 2003]. In the case of power and water, under-pricing of user fees do not allow recovery of costs even to meet costs of operation and maintenance and this leads to deteriorat-ing quality of water and power services to farmers. Strengthen-ing public institutions that provide public goods and services and making them cost-efficient can lead to both fiscal sustainability and long-term growth. These goals can be achieved in different ways such as privatisation, unbundling, decentralisation and contracting. Effective public institutions also require an adequate supply of trained and motivated personnel and investments in training to increase the supply.Another reason for slower implementation of reforms in India relates to the regulatory environment and the enforcement bureaucracy. Although streamlining the regulatory apparatus through de-licensing has begun, much inefficiency remains in place. Several private investment decisions still require government approval entailing long procedures encouraging corruption. During the reform years China relaxed regulations on mobility between rural and urban areas, which promoted the develop-ment of the non-farm sector and abetted economic migration. Recently, it has also started to relax the complex system control-ling broad-based personal mobility, removing state interference in private life and creating a more mobile and open social envi-ronment in tune with the freer economic setting.6 One of the fall-outs of these changes is the faster issue of passports and visas.Finally, a key factor in the effective implementation of reforms in China was the ability of the leadership to set both clear objectives and time frame for transition to the reformed regime [Ahluwalia 2002], no doubt helped by the centralisation of decision-making which minimises dissent. In the context of a highly pluralist society like India, consent is more difficult to achieve, and so neither clear objectives nor time frames for transition can be set. This has been the case with, for instance, phasing out of subsidies, tariff reduc-tion, price increases for economic services, etc. There is also a ten-dency towards populist policymaking in India, which is clear in the case of subsidies which although acknowledged as inefficient and iniquitous, have been tough to remove or minimise. This situation slows the pace of change in the short and medium term. Although democracy and participation have intrinsic value and are not mere instruments of development, the role of democracy in enhancing or hampering economic change and poverty reduction remains a complex subject for development research. Comparisons of China and India on these broad political matters may produce a fascinat-ing set of insights in the coming years. 10 ConclusionsA number of factors help to explain the differences in growth be-tween the two countries during the reform era: initial conditions, the sequencing and pace of reforms, and the political system, in-stitutions, and regulatory environment. Yet special mention must be made of the fact that China and India achieved remarkable development and growth even as aid as a percentage of GDP in

2001-2004): Agricultural Statistics at a Glance, Directorate of Economics and Statistics, New Delhi, http://www.agricoop.nic. in/stats.htm.

Huang, Jikun, C Chen, S Rozelle and F Tuan (1999): Trade Liberalisation and China’s Food Economy in the 21st Century: Implications to China’s National Food Security, paper available online http: www.aic.ucdavis.edu/research/rozelle.htm (accessed April 2004).

Dear Reader,

To continue reading, become a subscriber.

Explore our attractive subscription offers.

Click here

Back to Top