Policy Issues andRole of Banking Systemin Financial Inclusion
Financial exclusion remains a major issue in the unorganised sector. Expansion of services in this area by banks will not be very easy because of the special situation and needs of the unorganised sector. This article suggests that while structural solutions are expensive and nevertheless must be pursued, banks should think of designing a process response to the problem, drawing on the experiences and practices of the traditional lenders to the
unorganised sector.
N SRINIVASAN
T
The excluded are unorganised, and hence, difficult to cover; the volume of business offered by the sector is commercially insignificant; the widely dispersed nature and small individual requirements render services to the sector unviable; the economic value addition by the sector is not high, and hence loans given would turn into non-performing assets (NPAs) on account of high default rates; the financial constraints faced by the sector should be alleviated through welfare handouts; not by commercial loans.
Too Big to Fail
This paradigm is borne out of the conventional banking mindset which pursues big volumes and large clients with the underlying logic of too big to fail (TBTF). A large part of the population is therefore excluded from the business of banks under such a paradigm. It fits in very well with the limited network capacities of banks and the reduced staff strength post VRS. However, it is not the best response to the large number of unserved people who keep high expectations on the banking system.
The survey of indebtedness carried out by the NSSO reported that in 2002, three out of four rural households and four out of five urban households do not have a bank loan. In the 11 years from 1991 to 2002 the banking system added only 4 per cent of rural households as its customers. While there has been an increase in the number of small borrowal accounts in the decade 1995-2005, there is no perceptible increase in the number of priority sector loans. When seen against the backdrop of the estimated increase of 160 million people to the population in the decade 1995-2005, the increase in number of priority sector loans seems insignificant.
The developments in other sectors should be examined before analysing the performance of banking in its efforts at inclusion of those outside its portals. Most marketers – say, of automobiles, cell phones, white goods and brown goods have specific products and strategies targeted at the unorganised sector. If the ad spends are any indication, they seem to have a long-term positive view of this market. Initiatives such as the ITC e-choupal, Godrej Adhar, Mahindra Shublabh, HLL Shakthi, clearly target unorganised sectors and seek to bring them into a framework where their economic potential could be harvested. The corporate world has taken to rural areas and urban slums like never before in the past only because of their commercial significance. Why then do banks have such a different view on such a large numbers of economically active people?
Policy Gap
The second issue in the paradigm is that of network capacity and costs. It is true that the present branch network and staff strength would not be sufficient for business expansion. In the nine years between 1996 and 2005, the banking system reduced its employees strength by more than 10 per cent, but increased its branch network by 6.3 per cent and increased its client accounts (deposits and advances) by 21.2 per cent (Table 2). Such an expansion in business has been brought about through a rigorous cost-cutting exercise coupled with process refinement and automation. This kind of an increase in productivity in terms of client acquisition was made possible by the idle capacity then existing in the banking system but is not likely in future.
But when the Reserve Bank of India (RBI) and the government are seized of the objective of financial inclusion, the question faced by the financial sector in achieving financial inclusion is not one of whether but how.
Rural Finance Policy
At the policy level the authorities have yet to achieve finality on a rural finance policy, especially of a rural financial architecture in the post-reform scenario. Whatever has happened in rural finance so far whether self-helf group (SHG) bank linkage, introduction (and closure) of local area banks, regional rural banks (RRB),
Table 1: Small Borrowal Accounts and Priority Sector Accounts (1995-2005)
Year No of Small No of Priority Loan Sector Loan Accounts Accounts (Lakh) (Lakh)
1995-96 519.04 341.55 2004-05 711.06 342.58
Source: RBI website.
Table 2: Spread of Bank Network(1996-2005)
Year No of No of No of No of Branches Employees Deposit Loan (Lakh) Accounts Accounts (Lakh) (Lakh)
1996 64456 10.19 3920.09 566.72 2005 68549 9.00 4667.93 771.51
Source: RBI website.
Economic and Political Weekly July 28, 2007 mergers and consolidation, suggested use of correspondents, appear to be incremental and ad hoc; not a well designed and thought-out response to the problems faced by the rural areas. This lack of planning of a rural financial architecture and its linkage with the rest of the financial sector is at the core of the problems currently affecting the rural areas. This policy gap has resulted in tardy progress in financial inclusion and affected the quality of services. The speed of conversion of public sector banks into widely-held companies answerable to shareholders has not been matched by generation of alternatives in rural finance. Business lines that are less profitable cannot be expected to remain a priority of a shareholder-run commercial banking system.
At the country level, ensuring access to at least one member of each family for banking services would mean 200 million clients for the banking system. As against this, the number of loan accounts with the banking system is an estimated 125 million. If we expand the definition of financial inclusion to “providing access to all adult members of the population”, at the least the number of potential clients to be serviced would increase to about 600 million. All commercial banks put together carry 466 million deposit accounts in their books. There is a large gap between the number of potential and actual clients with the banking system.
Challenges Ahead
India had invested considerable resources in expanding its banking network. More than 60,000 branches of commercial banks and more than 1,00,000 primary agricultural credit societies (PACS) functioning as extended arms of cooperative banks and over 2,000 primary urban banks serve the people of the country, apart from several other formal financial institutions, big and small. This large infrastructure that has penetrated even remote rural areas is still able to serve only a small part of the potential clientele. If the potential clientele has to be served, even with minimal access, it is clear that the present infrastructure would not be sufficient. Firstly, the physical infrastructure would be a limitation in expanding the number of clients. Secondly, the staff required to deal with the expanded client base would be inadequate.
An analysis of the data relating to number of deposit accounts and loan accounts statewise captures the challenges in achieving financial inclusion. An attempt has been made to relate the number of deposit accounts and loan accounts of the scheduled commercial banks (which account for more than 85 per cent of total banking business in the country) with the census data pertaining to the year 2000-01. Across the country, as against 193.6 million households, 466.7 million deposit accounts are held with the commercial banks. On the surface, the data indicates that each household has more than two deposit accounts with the commercial banks (not reckoning the accounts that may be held with the cooperative banks). However, loan accounts were only 77.2 million in March 2005 indicating that about two out of five households had access to a loan facility from commercial banks. But these averages seem exaggerated once we recognise that a financial service is rendered to an individual and not to a household. Further an analysis of the statewise information reveals the disparity in coverage of financial services. Loan coverage: If we assume that financial inclusion would stand achieved when every adult has at least one deposit account, then we find that in 20 states, inclusion is yet to be achieved. There are 10 states in which more than half the adult population does not have a deposit account. In the case of loans, the position is even worse. The state with the best loan coverage (Tamil Nadu), reports that only one out of
every three adults enjoys a loan facility with a commercial bank (since the analysis is made on the basis of number of loan accounts, the possibility of multiple loans in the same name reducing coverage further has not been factored in). There are 15 states in which less than one in 10 adults has a loan account. This includes some of the larger states such as, Rajasthan, UP, Bihar, West Bengal, Jharkhand, Chhattisgarh, Madhya Pradesh and Gujarat. At the all-India level, only 13 per cent of the adult population enjoy a loan facility and 77 per cent have a deposit account. In the case of loans, even if we include the 45 million borrowers banking with the cooperatives, we find that against 600 million adults, hardly 122 million loan accounts exist. Branch network: The inferences from the foregoing analysis point to the challenges facing financial inclusion. Any effort or inclusion calls for extraordinary efforts. At a conservative estimate, a 400 per cent increase over the present number of accounts in the case of loans and a 50 per cent increase over the present number of deposit accounts may be needed. The financial infrastructure established in the rural areas as it stands today is not adequate to undertake this effort. A look at the load per branch in terms of deposit accounts and loan accounts provides certain pointers. The all-India average of deposit accounts per branch is around 6,500 and the loan accounts are around 1,100. The range across states in the case of deposit accounts per
Himal
Economic and Political Weekly July 28, 2007
branch is from a minimum of 2,038 in Mizoram to a maximum of 9,000 in Pondicherry (Table 3). The average per branch number of loan accounts ranges from a minimum of 500 in Meghalaya to a maximum of 2,500 in Tamil Nadu. Eleven states have deposit accounts per branch above all-India average. In the case of loans, 21 states have per branch loan account below the all-India average.
Assuming all the branches in the country could reach the best state’s average, calculations show that in the case of deposit accounts, we would still require 140 million more accounts to cover the unserved adults and 460 million more loan accounts to cover people unserved for want of branch network. While in the case of deposit accounts, it might be possible through incremental measures to bridge the gap, in the case of loan accounts, incremental measures may not be sufficient. Banks have to step up to a higher scale of operations by expanding their rural branch network. Certainly, this calls for a reversal of the trends seen in the recent years – that of closure of a number of rural branches by commercial banks. Such an expansion would entail significant additional costs. To ensure profitable rural operations in the face of additional costs, banks have to invest in radical innovations that would make branchless banking feasible. Know your clients: The aspect of costs (of both institutions and the clients) in expanding access to financial services needs some analysis. The rigour of know your client (KYC) norms, the need for diligent bookkeeping and the criticality of maintaining high standards of services would entail significant costs to the banks. As a proportion of business, these transaction costs are bound to be high in the case of small clients. Ideally, the banks should be permitted to price their products to ensure full cost recovery. Universal access: If the banks determine their prices on the basis of full cost recovery, would a typical client in the unorganised sector afford this kind of cost? The answer in most cases would be a clear no. In fact, banks have been using certain features such as a minimum balance in savings accounts, fees of different kinds in the case of loan accounts that would cover the overhead costs, a limitation of number of operations on smaller accounts, etc, as means of keeping costs under control. These practices result in hidden costs to the client. The RBI brought in the concept of “no frills” account to ensure that the clients do not have to pay hidden costs so that the clients’ costs of accessing services are affordable. When clients’ costs are set at affordable levels, banks would tend to limit the number of such clients; as at the end of the day, they have to post profits. What is clear is that there is an inherent conflict between the banks and their small clients in the matter of who will bear the costs of access to financial services. A solution needs to be found if universal access to financial services has to become a reality.
Currently, the debate on costs is limited to the expansion possibilities of banks at their current scale of operation. But if the entire unorganised sector population has to be linked to the banking system, the banks will have to scale up their operations, and increase their capacity by two to three times. This scaling up effort would involve significant investment costs as well which would have to be recovered. These costs, if passed on to the small clients could make their access to banks even more difficult.
Thus an introduction of universal access to financial services is not likely to be easy. This calls for certain decisions in the domain of public policy. Banks are being called upon to provide financial services to all types and manners of clients on lines similar to post office under “universal services obligation”. Recognising that financial infrastructure is a “public good”, both the RBI and the government of India should invest in creating the financial infrastructure required for access to financial services by one and all. This could be in the form of reimbursing capital investments of banks in expansion or an annual payment out of a Universal Service Obligation fund in proportion to the additional clientele covered from the unorganised sector. This would make the cost of access affordable to both the bankers and the clients. Financial inclusion as a public policy objective is meaningful only when costs of increasing outreach are borne in the initial period by the state.
While structural solutions are expensive, and nevertheless must be pursued, should not banks think of designing a process response to the problem? Banks achieved considerable progress in financial inclusion of large numbers cost effectively under the SHG bank linkage programme. An estimated 33 million households have been provided access to banks over the last 10 years, with a major part of the effort
Table 3: State-wise Pattern of Deposits, Loans and Branch Network
Name of | No of Deposits | No of Loans | No of Branches | Average Per | Average per |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
State | Per 100 | Per 100 | Per Lakh | Branch Deposit | Branch Loan |
Adults | Adults | Population | a/c | a/c |
J and K 91 7 9 5977 469 Himachal Pradesh 122 12 13 5273 503 Punjab 145 12 11 7283 610 Uttaranchal 107 11 11 5781 600 Haryana 100 10 8 7078 707 Rajasthan 57 8 6 5259 760 Uttar Pradesh 67 8 5 7536 914 Bihar 41 6 4 5304 737 Sikkim 65 11 11 3382 545 Arunachal Pradesh 46 6 6 4265 515 Nagaland 26 4 4 3795 548 Manipur 24 4 4 3679 641 Mizoram 36 8 10 2038 475 Tripura 55 14 6 5382 1392 Meghalaya 49 7 8 3486 497 Assam 51 6 5 6036 677 West Bengal 76 8 6 7430 799 Jharkhand 57 7 6 5831 743 Orissa 52 12 6 4720 1121 Chhattisgarh 43 6 5 4779 651 Madhya Pradesh 53 8 6 5104 765 Gujarat 88 8 8 6704 604 Maharashtra 93 17 7 7622 1407 Andhra Pradesh 89 22 7 7021 1700 Karnataka 99 24 10 5813 1420 Goa 371 19 27 7838 407 Kerala 143 26 11 7172 1282 Tamil Nadu 97 35 8 6892 2511 Pondicherry 142 21 9 9000 1311 India 77 13 7 6557 1110
Source: Banking statistics – RBI website, Population Statistics: GoI, 2001 Census Data, GoI website.
Economic and Political Weekly July 28, 2007
GUJARAT INSTITUTE OF DEVELOPMENT RESEARCH
Gota, Ahmedabad 380 060
ADVERTISEMENT NO. AAP/1/2007
GIDR a premier social science research institute supported by the ICSSR and the Government of Gujarat plans further expansion of research faculty. The Institute provides a congenial work environment, offers UGC pay scale and excellent career advancement prospects. The Institute also plans to commence a doctoral programme in social sciences shortly. Applications are invited for the following positions:
The minimum qualification for the posts of Professor, Associate Professor and Assistant Professor is a Ph.D in social sciences preferably, Economics, Sociology or Demography. For the post of Professor and Associate Professor, in addition to a Ph.D degree, the candidates should have at least ten and seven years of research experience respectively in a reputed institution and scholarly publications. The scholars should also have proven ability for conducting independent research. Those candidates who have submitted their Ph.D thesis could be considered for Associate faculty or Project Associate positions.
Candidates with specialisation or research interests in Natural Resources Management, Environmental Economics, Labour and Development Issues, Industrial economics, Urban issues, Tribal Development, Institutions and Governance will be preferred, though others are also welcome to apply.
Selection will be made on the basis of interview of short-listed candidates and if necessary the candidate would be asked to present a seminar. However, mere satisfying the eligibility norms does not entitle a candidate to be called for the interview. The Institute reserves the right to call only a limited number of candidates and the right to consider deserving scholars who may not have responded to the advertisement. Other qualifications being equal, preference would be given to SC, ST and BC candidates.
Interested Scholars may submit their application and Curriculum vitae to the undersigned along with a copy of three research papers and names and addresses of three referees within 15 days of publication of this advertisement. Those candidates who have responded to the earlier advertisement (No. APP/1/2006) need not apply. For details, visit web site www.gidr.ac.in
R. PARTHASARATHY
Director
Economic and Political Weekly July 28, 2007
being made in the last four years. Such process-solutions enable banks to cost effectively reach the unorganised sector. There is a need to look more deeply into group-based methodologies so that local communities participate in banking, absorb a part of the costs, eliminating the much-maligned bank charges.
Identifying new clients and bringing them to banks is the dominant content of financial inclusion initiatives. Here, apart from costs, staff capacities are also involved. The tasks of (a) identification of new clients, (b) enabling them to fulfil KYC norms, and (c) certification of the clients and banks’ compliance with KYC norms, could be outsourced to third party service providers. Such an agency could be an alliance of SHGs, or a mechanism set up by the panchayati raj institutions (PRIs) or any other credible source that could gather data, present it in a form suitable for the banks and certify the accuracy and veracity of the information. Such agencies have the potential of becoming credit information bureaus over a period of time that could be networked into a national level credit information exchange. Risk management: Defaults are inherent in banking business. Banking is all about identifying the risk, quantifying the same, designing a mitigation mechanism and pricing the product in such a manner that the risks are absorbed across the portfolio. Bankers have received periodic reminders of the fact that large loans are equally at risk and such large risks singularly affect banks. Financing a variety of activities under the unorganised sector could, in fact, be a very appropriate risk diversification mechanism.
Risk management practices in financing the unorganised sector have been predictably traditional. The measures consist of either asking for increased collateral that the borrower in the sector could ill-afford to bring, or ask for an increased own stake which s/he does not have. Otherwise, banks look for a subsidy scheme under which the borrower could be financed. Lastly, an increased interest rate to absorb the higher risk costs of dealing with this sector is applied to mitigate risks. Most of these conventional approaches would tend to exclude deserving customers and attract the desperate borrower who in most cases does not intend to repay. The group approach to lending to small borrowers has shown over the last few years that there are alternatives to conventional approaches to dealing with this sector. Cash flow-based lending approaches also hold out much promise of risk reduction as they reduce the need for dependence on external sources of funds for other productive purposes.
Innovation and Creativity
This is not to suggest that banks do not finance the marginalised and underserved people. There are a variety of governmentsupported, funded and subsidised programmes under which banks have lent a lot of money, albeit reluctantly. There are also initiatives like the SHG linkage programme under which banks have lent large sums voluntarily. These have proved that the unorganised sector is a commercial proposition for the banks; what we needed are product and process innovations that could effectively deal with the large number of small financial needs.
Innovation and creativity are the key words in the future of banking in general and in the coverage of clients that have not been served so far. The unorganised sector has been financed for a long time by traditional players – another set of unorganised people – with success. The village moneylender, landlord, petty trader, commission agent, input supplier, commodity procurer and a host of others with different role descriptions and functions, have been the backbone of unorganised sector. If many such players could do something successfully for a long time, why banks with professional expertise and financial strength could not do the same? The ideas on how to cover the rest of the unorganised sector and with profits should be drawn from the unorganised financiers. From there one could redesign products and delivery mechanisms that could increase the comfort level of bankers and bring such clients to banks. The task of servicing the unorganised sector could be outsourced to market intermediaries.
The market intermediaries are best placed to handle the outsourced work, as their knowledge of the local area, local economy and people is wide and deep. We should think of legitimising such market intermediaries to play a financial intermediary role, with or without risk participation. The RBI’s internal working group on microfinance has already spawned a few new ideas including use of franchisees, facilitators and banking correspondents. With the central bank adopting a positive and proactive stance for improving outreach of financial services to marginalised people and its recent focus on financial inclusion it should find ways of changing the current banking paradigm on unorganised sector.
The financially excluded are not an easy business prospect in waiting, just to be plucked. Many of these potential clients have to improve their capacities, before entering commercial activities. The issue is not merely of finance, with a finite banking solution. There are other facets, which need attention from the governments and community organisations. Creating opportunities for unorganised entrepreneurs to thrive through a facilitative policy framework falls in the domain of governments. Enterprise risk mitigation and management is another major aspect requiring attention. Provision of fair markets and access to markets through a combination of physical infrastructure and capacity-building is also a priority. The market is a hard place that has no gentle feelings for the unorganised sector or weaker sections in general. Non-governmental organisations (NGOs) have a particularly difficult role of preparing the budding entrepreneurs from the sector to compete in a market-oriented economy. Training bankers and influencing mindsets to look at the unorganised sector from a new perspective is the job of training institutions buttressed by senior management of banks.
Financial inclusion should not remain a daydream of a welfare state. It is a necessity if the country has to realise its economic potential. The country cannot afford to have an elite minority enjoying services with banks and a large unorganised majority in the cash and barter mode. This divide, apart from undermining economic growth could engender social tensions. Sustained growth of the nation and its continued prosperity depend critically on universal financial services coverage of all people. Banks are in a unique position to make the transition from a “cash market” to a payment system-driven economy and profit in the process.

Email: shrin54@gmail.com
Economic and Political Weekly
available at
Sundar News Agents
(Magazine Market) 158 D N Road, Shop No 6 Near Kelkar Hotel
Fort, Mumbai 400 001
Economic and Political Weekly July 28, 2007