ISSN (Print) - 0012-9976 | ISSN (Online) - 2349-8846

Articles by Jandhyala B G TilakSubscribe to Jandhyala B G Tilak

National Human Development Initiative

The finance minister in his budget speech stated that "high priority is being accorded to problem of the human resource development in the Ninth Plan". One of the important components of the 'National Human Development Initiative' announced in the Union Budget is education. Education is also recognised as an important item of 'basic human development needs' and is one of the items of the prime minister's special action plan. Do the programmes and financial resource allocations proposed in the Union Budget, and the Ninth Plan match these high sentiments expressed in favour of education? Answers to this question is attempted here examining the Draft Ninth Five-Year Plan 1997-2002, the Economic Survey 1998-99, and the Budget 1999-2000.

Student Loans as the Answer to Lack of Resources for Higher Education

Student loan programmes, as the answer to the problem of lack of public funds for higher education, are based on a questionable philosophy and unrealistic assumptions and are being launched in many developing countries with exaggerated expectations.

Five Decades of Underinvestment in Education

The need for strengthening the resource base for education is obvious. But the solutions that are being thought of are dangerous. Neither student fee increases nor the excessive reliance on external assistance for primary education is appropriate. A closer examination of policy choices is urgently needed.

Investment Gaps in Primary Education

Investment Gaps in Primary Education Jandhyala B G Tilak WHILE making an estimate of investment gaps in primary education in India, Ramachandran et al (1997) have commented on my study [Tilak and Kar 1994] that estimated requirement of resources for education by levels of education, including specifically elementary education (classes I-VIII/age-group 6-14), and by major states in India up to 2000 AD.1 Applying the unit costs of education (for a select few major items) provided by the government of West Bengal (GOWB) to all states in India and using National Sample Survey Organisation's (NSSO) data on enrolments and non-enrolments, Ramachandran et al (1997) estimated investment gaps in primary education in 1995. They seem to argue that this is the best method and that the method l had adopted has serious flaws. Their main criticism of my study refers to (a) my use of official enrolment figures instead of actual attendance rates by age- group, (b) use of 'expenditure per student' instead of 'costs of education', and (c) specification of the cost function. They also argue that ours was not a 'normative' method. I find these comments irrelevant and misleading, as I discuss them in Section 1. Research in this area is not abundant.2 Hence at the very outset I welcome the attempt by Ramachandran et al. But Ramachandran et at's approach and analysis have serious pitfalls, which are described in Section 2.

How Free is Free Pmiary Education in India

Jandhyala B G Tilak Based on data generated by the National Sample Survey Organisation on household expenditures on education this paper shows that households spend large sums of money on acquiring primary education. More specifically, it has been found that students pay tuition fee, examination fee and other fees even in government primary schools. The financial and material incentives provided by the government are found to be available only to a small fraction of students. There are large scale inter-state and inter-group (by gender and by region rural and urban) variations with respect to several aspects relating to public provision of incentives and also to the levels of household expenditure on education.

How Free is Free Primary Education in India

Based on data generated by the National Sample Survey Organisation on household expenditures on education this paper shows that households spend large sums of money on acquiring primary education. More specifically, it has been found that students pay tuition fee, examination fee and other fees even in government primary schools. The financial and material incentives provided by the government are found to be available only to a small fraction of students. There are large scale interstate and inter-group (by gender and by region rural and urban) variations with respect to several aspects relating to public provision of incentives and also to the levels of household expenditure on education.

Funding Higher Education in India

Jandhyala B G Tilak While stressing continued subsidising of higher education, a recent seminar also favoured foe hike for modest cost recovery and corporate financing of educational institutions.

The Pests Are Here to Stay-Capitation Fee in Disguise

The February 1993 judgment of the Supreme Court raises some important issues relating to capitation fee colleges in India, besides practically allowing charging of high fees of the order of more than Rs 1 lakh per student per year FOLLOWING the 'historic'' judgment delivered by the Supreme Court on Mohini Jain versus the state of Karnataka and others (July 30, 1992),1 several important issues have emerged onto surface, that we have intentionally and unintentionally avoided all these years regarding private higher educational institutions in India, particularly the capitation fee colleges. Subsequently several petitions and review petitions have also come to the high courts and the Supreme Court, some of which are still pending, and the government

Subsidies in Higher Education

GOVINDA RAO (1993) while replying to my criticism [Tilak 1993a] on his paper [Rao 1992] avoided important questions raised by me, concentrated on trivial and non-controversial issues, side-tracked the main issues and in all tried to mislead the readers. I wish to argue with Rao in the columns of the Weekly, for the policy issues raised by Rao are of crucial importance for the whole economy and its future; the paper is authored by an established researcher(s), comes from a respectable academic institute, published in an esteemed journal, and above all, it was originally commissioned by the union finance minister for policy use. Let me, however, briefly take up only the issues raised in the 'reply' by Rao. At the outset I may mention that 1 have raised four questions in my comment: (i) the reliability and relevance of the data source, and of the corresponding estimates on cost recovery in higher education, (ii) the base for 'economic pricing' of higher education, (iii) Rao's wisdom on the policy prescription to raise the rate of cost recovery to 50 per cent, and (iv) its superiority over other measures. Rao's response to none of these questions is satisfactory: on question (i) he seems to feel that the accounts presented to the state legislature and audited by the comptroller and auditor-general cannot but be right, and hence his estimates should also be right; on question (ii) Rao's 'economic pricing' means no more than 'fixing proper fees'; on question (iii) Rao did not bother to discuss on the quantum of cost recovery, or the recovery rate; he only tried to argue the need for (increased) cost recovery, with which one may not have much disagreement; and he says little oh question (iv) but for passing quick judgments.

Budgetary Reforms and Subsidies in Higher Education

Budgetary Reforms and Subsidies in Higher Education Jandhyala B G Tilak WHILE Govinda Rao (1992) examines several social and economic services regarding the current state of public subsidies and recovery, with a view to identifying the major problem areas and outlining the needed policy changes, I wish to comment on only one particular area, an area in which my comparative disadvantage is less, viz, public subsidies in education, particularly higher education. I attempt to show here that (i) Rao's estimate on recovery rate in higher education is far from correct, (ii) Rao's plea for economic pricing of sectors like education is not based on sound principles of public finance, (iii) Rao's suggestion regarding the desirable level of recovery rate is neither desirable nor feasible in the broad socioeconomic framework, and (iv) there are probably more efficient cost recovery strategy alternatives than the one suggested by Rao. However, from this single case of education, which is only one of the several areas Rao has covered in his paper, I do not question his whole analysis in general. That is left for those who are more familiar with the various sectoral and general aspects of public finances and budgetary subsidies.

Distribution of Education among Income Groups

Income Groups Jandhyala B G Tilak COMMENTING on my paper (August 13. 1983) K R Shah (October I, 1983) raised several issues, some of which require detailed response. However. I would also like to briefly discuss the other points raised In him.

Distribution of Education among Income Groups - An Empirical Analysis

Income Groups An Empirical Analysis Ajit K Dasgupta Jandhyala B G Tilak Based on a socio-economic survey of the West Godavari District of Andhra Pradesh in India, the hypothesis that the distribution of education is equitable is verified in this paper.

Pages

Back to Top